C.H.
(Clifford Hugh) Douglas (1879–1952),
economic theorist, was born in Stockport,
Cheshire, on 20 January 1879, the youngest son of Hugh Douglas, draper,
and his wife, Louisa Arderne Hordern.
Douglas was a complex and intensely
secretive character, and little is known of his life. What biographical
information he did release tended to magnify his importance, creating a
public image that in some respects differed significantly from the
reality. Having been educated at Stockport grammar school, he entered on
an engineering and mechanical career, and was a member of the Institution
of Electrical Engineers (1904–20) and of the Institute of Mechanical
Engineers (1918–36).
It is possible that his employment took him for a
time to India, where he claimed to have been chief engineer and manager of
the British Westinghouse Company, although the company has no record of
his having worked for the firm. In 1910, at the late age of thirty-one, he
went up to Pembroke College, Cambridge. In later life he was keen to give
the impression of having been educated there in the fullest sense, when in
fact he spent four terms only and left without taking a degree. During the
First World War he was taken on at the Royal Aircraft Establishment in
Farnborough, where he reorganized production and cost accounting. He was
promoted to temporary captain in the Royal Flying Corps on 1 January 1916,
and soon afterwards to temporary major on 1 June 1916.
Douglas had
already been reflecting on society's failure to exploit the full
possibilities of modern technology; his work at Farnborough suggested an
explanation of this, which in turn led to the theory of social credit. In
every productive establishment the amount of money issued in a given
period as wages, salaries, and dividends—which he took to be the amount
available to purchase the goods produced in that period—was less than the
collective price of those products. To remedy the supposed chronic
deficiency of purchasing power he advocated issuing additional money to
consumers, or subsidies to producers to enable them to set prices below
costs. By these devices, which came to be known as social credit,
production was to be liberated from the price system, inaugurating an era
of plenty, freedom, leisure, and human dignity, without altering the
system of private ownership, profit, and enterprise.
Convinced that
his analysis was the sole key to understanding and remedying the world's
ills, Douglas devoted himself to developing its implications and pressing
its claims. His critique of the economic system first appeared in articles
in The Organiser in 1917, and later in the
English Review (December 1918 – October 1919).
In the meantime he was introduced to the journalist A. R. Orage, editor of
the intellectual weekly New Age, which offered
another platform for his views. In time the journal became completely
devoted to advancing social credit theory. Orage's own critique of society
had anticipated Douglas's, and he became an enthusiastic convert to
Douglas's economic theory, publishing Douglas's first book,
Economic Democracy (1920), serially in the
New Age (June–August 1919) and collaborating
in his second, Credit-Power and Democracy
(1920). Douglas's utopian vision of society rejected conventional
politics, whether of the right or the left, as a means of change: ‘There
is no hope whatever in the hustings; but a modified credit-system could
transform the world in five years’ (Douglas,
Credit-Power, 86). In 1921 and 1922 these ideas attracted
considerable public attention but were opposed by socialist writers and
the Labour Party, which formally rejected social credit doctrine in 1922.
In 1923 Douglas was brought to Ottawa by some Canadian admirers to expound
his views to the Canadian House of Commons committee on banking and
commerce.
Public discussion of social credit declined in Britain
after 1922, but with the depression of the thirties it revived in greater
volume, supported now by the New Age, the
New English Weekly, Douglas's own weekly
Social Credit, and various pamphlets and
books, some of which went through several editions. ‘What gave the Douglas
movement its persistent strength, even after the complete fallacy of the
social credit monetary theory had been repeatedly demonstrated, was its
cutting denunciation of existing society and its epochal vision of a new
society’ (Macpherson, 96). Douglas testified to the Macmillan committee on
finance and industry (1930) and lectured as far afield as New Zealand and
Canada in 1934.
By the late thirties the British social credit
movement under Douglas's rather autocratic leadership had dwindled into an
esoteric sect. But it had struck roots in western Canada, where Douglas
had had a following from the early twenties. When he visited Alberta in
1934 he won such wide support that the ageing United Farmers government,
in spite of being sceptical about social credit, appointed him (early in
1935) principal reconstruction adviser to the government of Alberta, with
a two-year contract. However, the government was swept out of office by
the more zealous Social Credit League in the elections of August 1935.
Relations between Douglas and the new government soon became strained. He
resigned as adviser in 1936, and published his account of the matter in
The Alberta Experiment (1937). In this lengthy
work of self-justification Douglas did not conceal his contempt for the
Alberta legislators: it was they who had failed the theory of social
credit, and not the reverse. At the same time his writing showed deep
compassion for the poor and a refusal to accept that in a land ‘fertile,
rich, and reasonably developed’, such as Alberta, there should ever exist
‘desperate poverty at the lower end of the social scale, and economic and
political insecurity amongst all classes not in actual want’ (Douglas,
Alberta, 90). A back-benchers' revolt in the
province in 1937 compelled the government to ask Douglas's further help.
He sent two of his staff, who prepared legislation which, when enacted,
was invalidated by federal authorities. The provincial government remained
social credit in name but virtually abandoned Douglas's principles.
Douglas's earlier writings were remarkable for their reasoned protest
against the frustration of individuality by business civilization. But his
economic theory never surmounted his initial fallacy of reasoning from one
firm to the whole economy. And his social and political theory was
vitiated by his engineering concepts. He saw social credit ‘as an
engineering solution to an engineering problem’, and naïvely believed that
he had only to identify the solution for the necessary change to be
effected (Macpherson, 121). The failure of the political and financial
establishments to take up his ideas in Britain forced him to seek public
support, but when this too failed to realize his vision he was forced into
increasing isolation. Ultimately he could explain this failure only in
terms of a ‘world plot’ that aimed to undermine Christian civilization. He
was driven to attribute the thwarting of technology, and hence of human
freedom, to a conspiracy of world Jewry, freemasonry, international
finance, Bolshevism, and Nazism, and finally to denigrate democracy and
denounce the secret ballot. ‘He died a lonely and embittered man, cut off
even from the main body of his own supporters’ (Finlay, 88).
Douglas was married twice: first to Constance Mary, daughter of Edward
Phillips, of Royston House, Hertfordshire. His second wife was Edith Mary,
daughter of George Desborough Dale, of the Indian Civil Service; they had
one daughter. He was a fisherman and yachtsman, and for a time ran a
yacht-building shipyard at Swanwick, Southampton.
Douglas died in
his home in Fearnan, Scotland, on 29
September 1952; his second wife survived him.
Further details on this entry would be
welcome.
Errors and Omissions
|
|
The Forum
|
|
What's new?
|
We are looking for your help to improve the accuracy of The Douglas
Archives.
If you spot errors, or omissions, then
please do let us know
Contributions
Many articles are stubs which would benefit from re-writing.
Can you help?
Copyright
You are not authorized to add this page or any images from this page
to Ancestry.com (or its subsidiaries) or other fee-paying sites
without our express permission and then, if given, only by including
our copyright and a URL link to the web site.
|
|
If you have met a brick wall
with your research, then posting a notice in the Douglas Archives
Forum may be the answer. Or, it may help you find the answer!
You may also be able to help others answer their queries.
Visit the
Douglas Archives Forum.
2 Minute Survey
To provide feedback on the website, please take a couple of
minutes to complete our
survey.
|
|
We try to keep everyone up to date with new entries, via our
What's New section on the
home page.
We also use
the Community
Network to keep researchers abreast of developments in the
Douglas Archives.
Help with costs
Maintaining the three sections of the site has its costs. Any
contribution the defray them is very welcome
Donate
Newsletter
If you would like to receive a very occasional newsletter -
Sign up!
Temporarily withdrawn.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|